Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T21:47:38.538Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The money array; or, show me the debtor

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2023

Samuel A. Chambers*
Affiliation:
Johns Hopkins University, USA
*
Corresponding author: Samuel A. Chambers, Department of Political Science, Johns Hopkins University, 3400 N. Charles Street, Baltimore, MD 21218, USA. Email: samchambers@jhu.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Money is neither a thing nor a concept. Rather, as many writers have rightly suggested, money is a relation. But what kind of relation? This articles refuses the now seemingly common-sense notion that money is an ‘institution’ or a ‘public good’. Instead, it insists on specifying money as a concrete relation between creditor and debtor. To grasp money in both its practical and conceptual complexity, we must see it as an array. The money array is comprised of four elements: (1) a token that symbolizes the money relation; (2) a creditor who holds the token; (3) a debtor on whom the token makes a claim; (4) a denomination, i.e., the named quantity of credit/debt. The money array makes clear that no form of the money stuff - as money, i.e., as part of the money relation - ever possesses any positive, intrinsic value. The raison d’être of the money stuff - of any coin, note, bill, check, or digital token - is not to contain, have, or incarnate value. Money has no value. The value element of the money relation never lies in the money stuff, but rather can only be located across the entire money array.

Type
Keynote article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-No Derivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits noncommercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
© 2023 The Author(s)

References

Aglietta, M. and Orléan, A. (eds.) (1998) La Monnaie Souveraine. Paris: Éditions Odile Jacob.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aglietta, M. (2018) Money: 5,000 Years of Debt and Power. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Aristotle (2019) Nicomachean Ethics. Third edition. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett.Google Scholar
Aristotle (2017) Politics: A New Translation. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett.Google Scholar
Bryan, D., and Rafferty, M. (2006) Capitalism With Derivatives: A Political Economy of Financial Derivatives, Capital and Class. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, S.A. (2023) Money Has No Value. Berlin: De Gruyter.Google Scholar
Cencini, A. (1988) Money, Income, and Time: A Quantum-Theoretical Approach. London: Pinter.Google Scholar
Del Mar, A. (1896) The Science of Money. Second edition. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Drumm, C. (2021) The Difference That Money Makes: Sovereignty, Indecision, and the Politics of Liquidity. E-Scholarship: University of California. https://escholarship.org/uc/item/57h0m1x1.Google Scholar
Eich, S. (2022) The Currency of Politics: The Political Theory of Money from Aristotle to Keynes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Fisher, I. (1911) The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit, Interest, and Crises. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hayes, M.G. (2018) The liquidity of money. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 42(5): 1205–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawtrey, R.G. (1919) Currency and Credit. London: Longmans, Green, and Co.Google Scholar
Innes, A.M. (1913) What is money? Banking Law Journal, 30: 377408.Google Scholar
Innes, A.M. (1914) The credit theory of money. Banking Law Journal, 31: 151–68.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (1996) Money is a social relation. Review of Social Economy, 54(4): 507–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingham, G. (2000) ‘Babylonian madness’: On the historical and sociological origins of money. In: Smithin, J. (ed.) What Is Money? London: Routledge, 1641.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (2004) The Nature of Money. Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (2006) Further reflections on the ontology of Money: Responses to Lapavitsas and Dodd. Economy and Society, 35(2): 259–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingham, G. (2012) Revisiting the credit theory of money and trust. In: Pixley, J. (ed.) New Perspectives on Emotions in Finance: The Sociology of Confidence, Fear, and Betrayal. London: Routledge, 121–39.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (2015) ‘The Great Divergence’: Max Weber and China's ‘missing links’. Max Weber Studies, 15(2): 160–91.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (2018) A critique of Lawson's ‘Social positioning and the nature of money’. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 42(3): 837–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingham, G. (2020) Money: Ideology, History, Politics. Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Kelton, S. (2020) The Deficit Myth: Modern Monetary Theory and the Birth of the People's Economy. New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1930) A Treatise on Money. Two volumes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Knapp, G.F. (1924) The State Theory of Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lau, J. (2006) The capitalist development of China: A monetary and financial analysis. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Lavoie, M. (2013) The monetary and fiscal nexus of neo-chartalism: A friendly critique. Journal of Economic Issues, 47(1): 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, T. (2016) Social positioning and the nature of money. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 40(4): 961–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, T. (2022) Two conceptions of the nature of money: Clarifying differences between MMT and money theories sponsored by social positioning theory. real-world economics review, 101.Google Scholar
Levine, M. (2018) Why banking makes everyone so uncomfortable. Bloomberg, 10 April. Available at: <https://www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2018-04-10/why-banking-makes-everyone-so-uncomfortable>. Accessed 5 April 2023..+Accessed+5+April+2023.>Google Scholar
Levine, M. (2022) The crypto story. Bloomberg Businessweek, 31 October. Available at: <https://www.bloomberg.com/features/2022-the-crypto-story/>. Accessed 17 December 2022..+Accessed+17+December+2022.>Google Scholar
Macleod, H.D. (1889) The Theory of Credit: Volume 1. London: Longmans, Green, and Co.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N.G. (2010) Macroeconomics. Seventh edition. New York: Worth Publishers.Google Scholar
Mariz, P. (2023) Blockchain for everyone. Available at: <https://inquisitivists.s3.us-west-2.amazonaws.com/Blockchain_For_Everyone.pdf/>. Accessed 31 January 2023..+Accessed+31+January+2023.>Google Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2011) The New Lombard Street: How the Fed Became the Dealer of Last Resort. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2012) The inherent hierarchy of money. Paper prepared for Duncan Foley festschrift volume and conference, 20-21 April 2012. Available at: <https://ieor.columbia.edu/files/seasdepts/industrial-engineering-operations-research/pdf-files/Mehrling_P_FESeminar_Sp12-02.pdf>. Accessed 28 January 2023..+Accessed+28+January+2023.>Google Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2016) The economics of money and banking. Handout for ECON V3265, Barnard College, Columbia University, Fall Semester.Google Scholar
Mehrling, P. (2017) Financialization and its discontents. Finance and Society, 3(1): 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minsky, H. (2008) Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Morgan, J. (2023) Systemic stablecoin and the brave new world of digital money. Cambridge Journal of Economics, beac060.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peacock, M. (2013) Introducing Money. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J.A. (1956) Money and the social product. International Economic Papers, 6: 148211.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J.A. (2006) History of Economic Analysis. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seaford, R. (2004) Money and the Early Greek Mind: Homer, Philosophy, Tragedy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sgambati, S. (2022) Who owes? Class struggle, inequality and the political economy of leverage in the twenty-first century. Finance and Society, 8(1): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmel, G. (2004) The Philosophy of Money. Third edition. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, F.A. (1879) Money in Its Relations to Trade and Industry. New York: Henry Holt.Google Scholar
Wray, L.R. (1998) Understanding Modern Money: The Key to Full Employment and Price Stability. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Wray, L.R. (2004) Conclusion: The credit money and state money approaches. In: Wray, L.R. (ed.) Credit and State Theories of Money: The Contributions of A. Mitchell Innes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 223–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wray, L.R. (2022) Making Money Work for Us: How MMT Can Save America. Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Zelizer, V. (2000) Fine tuning the Zelizer view. Economy and Society, 29(3): 383–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar