Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-wq2xx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T19:17:43.369Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From credit to debt: A political history of English sovereign finance and money from the seventh century to the seventeenth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2023

Nicholas Dorn*
Affiliation:
Institute of Advanced Legal Studies, UK
*
Corresponding author: Institute of Advanced Legal Studies, University of London, 17 Russell Square, London WC1B 5DR, UK. Email: nicholas.dorn@sas.ac.uk.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

This article provides a new perspective on sovereign finance and money in England from pre-modern to early modern times. Re-reading the literature on sovereign fiscality through the lens of sovereign jurisdictions and religious authority, it describes two distinct forms of sovereign finance: the rise and fall of sovereign credit from the seventh to eleventh century, followed by sovereign debt developing from the eleventh century into ‘modern’ sovereign debt from the seventeenth century onwards. In the early Anglo Saxon period, sovereign credit was given and received in non-monetised forms. It was when sovereign jurisdictions became too wide for labour and bulky produce to travel that tax was monetised. However, the monetisation of credit undermined the very sovereign-subject relation on which sovereign credit was based. After the introduction of short-term sovereign debt by the Normans, for the next five hundred years, the two distinct fiscal mechanisms of sovereign credit and sovereign debt ran in parallel, although the latter was restrained by the church's prohibition of usury. In the seventeenth century, sovereign credit and sovereign debt became conjoined elements within one fiscal system, rather than separate mechanisms.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-No Derivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits noncommercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
© 2019 The Author(s)

References

Abrams, L. (2003) The early Danelaw: Conquest, transition and assimilation. In: Hericher, A.-M. (ed.) La Progression des Vikings: des raids à la colonisation. University of Rouen, 5770.Google Scholar
Abrams, L. (2012) Diaspora and identity in the Viking age. Early Medieval Europe, 20(1): 1738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, M. (2012) Mints and Money in Medieval England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angelucci, C., Meraglia, S. and Voigtländer, N. (2017) The Medieval Roots of Inclusive Institutions: From the Norman Conquest of England to the Great Reform Act. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Bell, A., Brooks, C. and Moore, T. (2009) Interest in medieval accounts: Examples from England, 1272-1340. History, 94(316): 411–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, A., Brooks, C. and Moore, T. (2014) The credit relationship between Henry III and merchants of Douai and Ypres. Economic History Review, 67(1): 123–45.Google Scholar
Beggs, M. (2017) The state as a creature of money. New Political Economy, 22(5): 463–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bholat, D. (2013) Review of Martin Allen, Mints and Money in Medieval England. Financial History Review, 20(1): 106–09.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bisschop, W. (2001/1896) The Rise of the London Money Market, 1640-1826. Kitchener: Batoche Books. Also available at: <http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/bisschop/money.pdf/>.Google Scholar
Brewer, J. (1989) The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688-1789. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Boucoyannis, D. (2015) No taxation of elites, no representation: State capacity and the origins of representation. Politics and Society, 43(3): 303–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boy, N. (2017) Finance-security: Where to go? Finance and Society, 3(2): 208–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. (ed.) (1991) The Anglo-Saxons. Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
Charles-Edwards, T. (1989) Early medieval kingship in the British Isles. In: Bassett, S. (ed.) The Origins of Anglo-Saxon Kingdoms. Leicester: University of Leicester Press, 2839.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (2007) The long march of history: Farm wages, population, and economic growth, England 1209-1869. Economic History Review, 60(1): 97135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, G. (2002) A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day. Cardiff: University of Wales.Google Scholar
Desan, C. (2005) The market as a matter of money: Denaturalizing economic currency in American constitutional history. Law and Social Inquiry, 30(1): 160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desan, C. (2014) Making Money: Coin, Currency, and the Coming of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desan, C. (2016) Money as a legal institution. In: Fox, D. and Ernst, W. (eds.) Money in the Western Legal Tradition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dickson, P. (1967) The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 1688-1756. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Gillingham, J. (1990) Chronicles and coins as evidence for levels of tribute and taxation in late tenth- and early eleventh-century England. The English Historical Review, 105(417): 939–50.Google Scholar
Graeber, D. (2011) Debt: The First 5,000 Years. London: Melville House.Google Scholar
Grierson, P. (1977) The Origins of Money. London: Athlone Press.Google Scholar
Hart, M. ‘t, Brandon, P. and Sánchez, R. (2018) Introduction: Maximising revenues, minimising political costs—Challenges in the history of public finance of the early modern period. Financial History Review, 25(1): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, C. (1940) The English Revolution 1640. London: Lawrence and Wishart.Google Scholar
van Houts, E. (1995) The Norman conquest through European eyes. English Historical Review, 110(438): 832–53.Google Scholar
Huppert, G. (1986) After the Black Death: A Social History of Early Modern Europe. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (2004) The Nature of Money. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Innes, A. (1914) The credit theory of money. Banking Law Journal, 31:151–68.Google Scholar
Jesch, J. (2015) The Viking Diaspora. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, S. (1993) Transaction costs, institutional change, and the emergence of a market economy in later Anglo-Saxon England. Economic History Review, 46(4): 658–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiser, E. and Barzel, Y (1991) The origins of democracy in England. Rationality and Society, 3(4): 396422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, A. (1947) Money as a creature of the state. American Economic Review, 37(2): 312–17.Google Scholar
Lyon, B. (1951) The money fief under the English Kings, 1066-1485. English Historical Review, 66(259): 161–93.Google Scholar
Maddicott, J. (1989) Trade, industry and the wealth of King Alfred. Past & Present, 123: 351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacDonald, J. (2001) Travel and communications networks in late Saxon Wessex: A review of the evidence. MPhil dissertation, University of York.Google Scholar
Manning, B. (1975) The peasantry and the English revolution. Journal of Peasant Studies, 2(2): 133–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maurer, B. (2013) David Graeber's Wunderkammer, Debt: The First 5,000 Years. Anthropological Forum, 23(1): 7993.Google Scholar
Mount, F. (2015) Back to Runnymede. London Review of Books, 37(8): 1518.Google Scholar
Munro, H. (2003) The medieval origins of the financial revolution: Usury, rentes, and negotiability. International History Review, 25(3): 505–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munro, H. (2011) Usury, Calvinism, and credit in protestant England: From the sixteenth century to the Industrial Revolution. Working Paper No. 439. Department of Economics, University of Toronto.Google Scholar
O'Brien, P. (1988) The political economy of British taxation, 1660-1815. Economic History Review, 41(1): 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, P. (2011) The nature and historical evolution of an exceptional fiscal state and its possible significance for the precocious commercialization and industrialization of the British economy from Cromwell to Nelson. Economic History Review, 64(2): 408–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Padgett Walsh, K. (2018) Transforming usury into finance: Financialization and the ethics of debt. Finance and Society, 4(1): 4159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palliser, D. (1993) Domesday Book and the ‘Harrying of the North’. Northern History, 29(1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peacock, M. (2003) State, money, catallaxy: Underlaboring for a chartalist theory of money. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26(2): 205–25.Google Scholar
Pincus, S. (2009) 1688: The First Modern Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Postan, M. (1950) Some economic evidence of declining population in the later Middle Ages. Economic History Review, 2(3): 221–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spear, D. (1982) The Norman Empire and the secular clergy, 1066-1204. Journal of British Studies, 21(2): 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sussman, N. and Yafeh, Y. (2006) Institutional reforms, financial development and sovereign debt: Britain 1690-1790. Journal of Economic History, 66(4): 906–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, R. (2016) Periodic recoinage as a monetary tax: Conditions for the rise and fall of the Bracteate economy. Economic History Review, 69(4): 1108–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roach, L. (2016) Æthelred the Unready. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Rubenstein, J. (1999) Liturgy against history: The competing visions of Lanfranc and Eadmer of Canterbury. Speculum, 74(2): 279309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storrs, C. (ed.) (2016) The Fiscal-Military State in the Eighteenth Century: Essays for P.G.M. Dickson. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Treharne, E. (2017) English in the post-conquest period. In: Pulsiano, P. (ed.) A Companion to Anglo-Saxon Literature. Wiley-Blackwell Online, 401–41.Google Scholar
Wareham, A. (2012) Fiscal policies and the institution of a tax state in Anglo-Saxon England within a comparative context. Economic History Review, 65(3): 910–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, T. (2015) Landscape and warfare in Anglo-Saxon England and the Viking campaign of 1006. Early Medieval Europe, 23(3): 329–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wray, L. (2010) Alternative approaches to money. Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 11(1): 2949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, D. (2015) Early medieval settlement and social power: The middle Anglo-Saxon ‘home farm’. Medieval Archaeology, 59(1): 2446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, J. (1999) British government borrowing in wartime, 1750-1815. Economic History Review, 52(2): 355–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar